Business Economics And Managerial Decision Making.pdf

(4362 KB) Pobierz
165578594 UNPDF
BUSINESS
ECONOMICS AND
MANAGERIAL
DECISION MAKING
Trefor Jones
Manchester School of Management
UMIST
165578594.001.png
4 PART I g CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND BUSINESS OBJECTIVES
INTRODUCTION
Firms are major economic institutions in market economies. They come in all shapes
and sizes, but have the following common characteristics:
g
Owners.
Managers.
g
Objectives.
g
g
Apoolofresources(labour,physicalcapital,¢nancialcapitalandlearnedskillsand
competences) to be allocated roles by managers.
g
Administrative or organizational structures through which production is
organized.
g
Performance assessment by owners, managers and other stakeholders.
Whatever its size, a ¢rm is owned by someone or some group of individuals or organiza-
tions.
These are termed shareholders and they are able to determine the objectives and
activities of the ¢rm. They also appoint the senior managers who will make day-to-day
decisions. The owners bear the risks associated with operating the ¢rm and have the
right to receive the residual income or pro¢ts. Where ownership rights are dispersed,
control of the ¢rm may not lie with the shareholders but with senior managers. This
divorce between ownership and control and its implication for the operation and
performance of the ¢rm is at the centre of many of the issues dealt with in this book.
OWNERSHIP STRUCTURES
The dominant model of the ¢rm in Western economies is the limited liability company
owned by shareholders, but the form varies signi¢cantly between countries. In some
countries the control rights of the owners are limited by powers given to stakeholders
who may share in the appointment and supervision of managers and in the determina-
tion of the enterprise’s objectives. In Germany, for example, large companies recognize
the role of workers and other groups by giving them half the positions on the
supervisory board that oversees the management board (Douma 1997). There are also
¢rms owned by members and operated as co-operative or mutual enterprises and some
owned by national and local government.
The notion that privately owned enterprises should be run in the interests of share-
holders is not a characteristic of companies in all advanced economies. Yoshimori
(1995) proposed that shareholder companies can be classi¢ed as follows:
g
Monistic ^ where the company serves a single interest group, normally share-
holders. These types of companies are commonly found in the UK and the USA.
g
Dualistic ^ where the company serves two interest groups. Shareholders are the
165578594.002.png
CHAPTER 1 g OWNERSHIP CONTROL AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 5
primary group but employees’ interests are also served. These types of companies
are commonly found in France and Germany.
g
Pluralistic ^ where the company serves the interests of stakeholders in the company
and not just shareholders. Employee and supplier interests may be paramount.
Such companies are found in Japan.
Since Yoshimori’s study some commentators have argued that there has been some
degree of convergence between European and Anglo-American forms of corporate
organizations because of greater international competition between enterprises.
Likewise, commercial and economic forces in Japan have put signi¢cant pressure on
companies to reduce the emphasis on the long-term employment of sta¡ and place
greater emphasis on pro¢tability.
PATTERNS OF SHAREHOLDING
The pattern of share ownership varies between countries and with time. In the UK and
the USA, ownership is more widely dispersed than in continental Europe and Japan
where it is more concentrated.
UK share ownership
Table 1.1 presents data on share ownership in the UK from 1963 to 2001.
Table 1.1 Shareholding in the UK
Owners
1963
1975
1989
1994
1997
2001
(%)
(%)
(%)
(%)
(%)
(%)
Individuals
54.0
37.5
20.6
20.3
16.5
14.8
Institutions
30.3
48.0
58.5
60.2
56.3
50.0
Of which:
Pension funds
6.4
16.8
30.6
27.8
22.1
16.1
Insurance companies
10.0
15.9
18.6
21.9
23.6
20.0
Companies
5.1
3.0
3.8
1.1
1.2
1.0
Overseas
7.0
5.6
12.8
16.3
24.0
31.9
Others
3.6
5.9
4.3
3.1
2.0
2.3
Total
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
Source Compiled by author using data from:
CSO (1993) Share register survey 1993, Economic Trends, No 480, London, HMSO
CSO (1995) Share Ownership, London, HMSO
CSO (1999) Share ownership, Economic Trends, No 543, London, HMSO
National Statistics (2002) Share Ownership 2001, http://www.statistics.gov.uk
165578594.003.png
6 PART I g CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND BUSINESS OBJECTIVES
Table 1.2 Structure of share ownership in Europe 2000
Type of investor
France
Germany
Italy
Spain
UK
(%)
(%)
(%)
(%)
(%)
Individuals
8
16
25
30
16
Private ¢nancial enterprises
29
18
20
14
48
Private non-¢nancial organizations
21
40
25
20
3
Public sector
6
6
15
0
0
Foreign investors
36
20
15
36
32
Unidenti¢ed
1
Total
100
100
100
100
100
Source Compiled by author using data from FESE (2002) Share Ownership Structure in Europe 2002, Brussels,
http://www.fese.be
The key features are:
g
The largest group of domestic owners of company shares are ¢nancial institutions.
g
Financial institutions’ share of ownership increased between 1963 and 1997, but
fell to 50% in 2001.
g
Individual ownership of shares has been in long-term decline and fell to 14.8% in
2001.
g
Overseas ownership of UK companies has increased and stood at 31.9% in 2001.
This trend re£ects the growing internationalisation of the asset portfolios held by
¢nancial institutions.
Shareholding in Europe
Comparative data for the ownership of shares in France, Germany, Italy, Spain and the
UK for the year 2000 are presented in Table 1.2. It shows that in each country the
structures are di¡erent in broad terms compared with the UK:
g
Holdings by ¢nancial institutions are lower.
g
Holdings by non-¢nancial companies are more important, particularly in Germany.
g
Individual ownership is more important in Italy and Spain, but less so in France.
g
Foreign owners are more important in France and Spain, but less signi¢cant in
Germany and Italy.
CLASSIFYING FIRMS AS OWNER OR MANAGEMENT CONTROLLED
The pattern of share ownership at company level varies widely. In the UK, quoted
companies ownership is generally described as being widely dispersed among large
numbers of shareholders. The largest shareholder often owns 5% or less of the stock
165578594.004.png
CHAPTER 1 g OWNERSHIP CONTROL AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 7
and a signi¢cant proportion is owned by non-bank ¢nancial institutions. The board of
directors typically own a tiny proportion of the shares, often much less than 0.5%.
Thus, managers rather than owners control many medium and large-sized companies
and set the ¢rm’s objectives. In France and Germany shareholding tends to be more
concentrated with greater blocks of shares held by companies and banks. According to
Denis and McConnell (2003) concentrated ownership structures are more likely to be
found in most countries in contrast to the dispersed ownership patterns that are
typicalonlyoftheUKandtheUSA.
How then can companies be classi¢ed as owner or managerially controlled? If a
single shareholder holds more than 50% of the stock, assuming one vote per share,
then they can outvote the remaining shareholders and control the company. If the
largest shareholder owns slightly less than 50% of the equity then they can be
outvoted if the other shareholders formed a united front. If the majority of shareholders
do not form a united front or do not vote, then an active shareholder with a holding of
substantially less than 50% could control the company.
Berle and Means (1932), who ¢rst identi¢ed the divorce between ownership and
control, argued that a stake of more than 20% would be su⁄cient for that shareholder
to control a company but less than 20% would be insu⁄cient and the company would
be management-controlled. Radice (1971) used a largest shareholding of 15% to
classify a ¢rm as owner-controlled; and a largest shareholder owning less than 5% to
classify a ¢rm as managerially controlled. Nyman and Silberston (1978) severely
criticized the ‘‘cut-o¡ ’’ or threshold method of assessing control and argued that the
distribution and ownership of holdings should be examined more closely. They
emphasized that there was a need to recognize coalitions of interests, particularly of
families, that do not emerge from the crude data.
Cubbin and Leech (1983) also criticized the simple cut-o¡ points for classifying
¢rms. They argued that control was a continuous variable that measures the
discretion with which the controlling group is able to pursue its own objectives
without being outvoted by other shareholders. Management controllers, they argued,
would be expected to exhibit a higher degree of control for any given level of sharehold-
ing than would external shareholders.
They then developed a probabilistic voting model in which the degree of control is
de¢ned as the probability of the controlling shareholder(s) securing majority support
in a contested vote. Control is de¢ned as an arbitrary 95% chance of winning a vote.
This ability depends on the dispersion of shareholdings, the proportion of shareholders
voting and the probability of voting shareholders supporting the controlling group.
The likelihood of the controlling group winning increases as the proportion voting
falls and the more widely held are the shares. Applying their analysis to a sample of
85 companies, they concluded that with a 10% shareholder turnout, in 73 companies
less than a 10% holding was necessary for control and in 37 companies with a 5%
turnout, less than a 5% holding was necessary for control.
Control of a company is therefore a function of the following factors:
g
Thesizeofthelargestholding.
g
The size and distribution of the remaining shares.
g
The willingness of other shareholders to form a voting block.
Zgłoś jeśli naruszono regulamin